04Recognise the contribution from the rest of the country

An implication of the geography of economic activity is that some places are much better positioned to benefit from business rates growth than others. In 2015-16, a third of all business rates was raised in only 23 local authorities – 11 of which were in London – (Figure 8), and more than two thirds of all business rates generated in England were in cities.

Figure 8: Top local authorities for business rates collection, 2015-2016

DCLG, National non-domestic Rates collected in England, 2015-16

As a result, trying to incentivise non-commercial areas to attract more businesses and reward such behaviours is likely to be ineffective. At the same time, the expected financial reliance on business rates means that these places need to find sustainable alternative sources of funding.

Acknowledging the fact that non-city areas are less able to increase their business rates, and understanding the role these places play in the overall economy, can help shape additional specifications to the system to allow them to benefit from it.

Pooling business rates

There is increasing recognition that urban local authorities are not individual economies but instead that each place plays a role in its wider city economy. While jobs tend to concentrate in specific areas – typically cities and city centres – workers tend to be more widely spread, with many living in surrounding local authorities. In 2011, two-thirds of workers based in a city centre in England and Wales lived in another local authority.

But because business rates are a tax on commercial property, only local authorities where businesses are located get revenues. This creates a mismatch between where the tax is generated and where revenues are spent in local services. Box 6 illustrates this with the case of Greater Manchester.

Box 6: Business rates revenues in Greater Manchester

Greater Manchester is a good example of an integrated economy. In 2011, only 38 per cent of Manchester local authority’s workers lived in the local authority and 46 per cent lived elsewhere in Greater Manchester.

As shown in Figure 9, more than 20 per cent of the economically active population of Trafford worked in Manchester, as did one in six working age residents of Salford and Tameside. But as work is located in Manchester, business rates are generated and collected there.

And this can be an issue for local finance. As shown in Figure 10, some local authorities such as Trafford and Manchester generate large amount of business rates per inhabitant (measured by business rates receipts) and have relatively low spending needs per head (measured as revenue expenditure per capita). By contrast, Tameside, Oldham and Rochdale provide workers to Manchester’s economy and have large expenditure needs, but do not generate much in business rates locally.

Figure 9: Share of economically active residents working in Manchester

Source: Census, 2011

Figure 10: Business rates receipts per capita and revenue expenditure per capita in Greater Manchester, 2016-2017

Source: DCLG, NNDR1 2016-2017; Revenue Account (RA) 2016-17

Pooling business rates revenues across city regions could help address this mismatch in tax and spend.13 In particular pooling would:

  • Allow surrounding local authorities that contribute to the economy through the supply of workers to the central area, to benefit from the growth in the city
  • Avoid negative competition between surrounding areas for investment
  • Provide a better allocation of funds for growth. Pooling all funds into one pot allows investment decisions to be taken at a city-region level, rather than at a local authority one, with higher economic and financial benefits.

Local authorities’ decision of whether or not to pool business rates will be affected by many factors, including local politics and the type of powers that will be on the table for devolution. But on a purely fiscal point of view, local authorities would only be willing to pool if they could get better financial or economic returns. This leaves two possibilities. The first is to ensure the pooling system has additional incentives to make it a more financially attractive solution than the status quo. This could include local rebates or the ability for authorities to have more flexibility over the multiplier. The second is for Government to enforce pooling, on the basis that it would achieve a better outcome to the wider city-region.

Support places that can’t generate enough business rates

For those places outside city-regions, the concentration of the economy in cities and their more limited ability to generate business rates growth would leave them with a high level of dependence on the system. This is why places that do not generate enough rates to cover for their services still need a national system of top-up and tariffs.

In this context of devolution, redistribution could be made more efficient by removing the cap on the business rates yield. As devolution could incentivise cities to generate more business rates, removing the cap would allow for more money to be redistributed at each reset of the system. This is why removing the cap is not only important from an incentive point of view, it can also help ensure the viability of the redistribution system.

 

 

Footnotes

  • 13 Pooling currently exists but has so far mainly been used as a mechanism to allow local authorities to avoid paying a levy on disproportionate growth, rather than encouraging a more integrated redistribution of business rates. The last Government was however clear that the levy will be dropped, meaning that there would be less reason for local authorities to pursue pooling in its current form, and leaving room for new pooling arrangements.